Antitrust Compliance Programs Under the Guidelines:
Initial Observations From
the Government's Viewpoint
By Neil E. Roberts
(reprinted from Corporate Conduct
Quarterly, Vol. 2 No. 1)
Compliance programs now play formal,
indeed formulaic, roles in sentencing organizations under the United States Sentencing
Guidelines. Under Section 8C2.5 of the Guidelines, effective November 1, 1991, the
existence of an "effective program to prevent and detect violations of the law"
is a significant factor in calculating a convicted corporation's "culpability
score," which under the Guidelines' calculus for sentencing organizations directly
affects both maximum and minimum fines.
The effect is substantial; depending on
other factors, credit for an effective program could reduce a corporation's maximum
antitrust fine by more than 50 percent. Antitrust compliance programs - long recommended
by inside and outside counsel - have truly come into their own.
The Guidelines (see Sec. 8Al.2 Commentary)
provide considerable detail, not to be repeated here, as to what the Sentencing Commission
means by an "effective" compliance program. They set out seven fairly specific
steps that "due diligence" in seeking to prevent and detect criminal conduct by
employees requires "at a minimum," and further describe other relevant factors
bearing on the precise actions that corporations should take to claim credit for a
compliance program - albeit one that failed to detect and prevent the instant offense - at
the time of sentencing.
Notwithstanding the Guidelines'
considerable guidance in this area, it is likely that even more specific Antitrust
Division policies and positions on credit for compliance programs will evolve over time
with exposure and experience rather than be hatched full-fledged at the first affected
sentencing. Nonetheless, and without intending to set out any list of minimum compliance
program requirements, I would offer a few general predictions.
First, the Division is likely to take
quite seriously the Guidelines' disqualification from compliance program credit of any
organization whose high level personnel (including individuals responsible for the
administration of the compliance program) participated in, condoned, or were willfully
ignorant of the offense. Who should be considered "high level" personnel and
what constitutes "willful ignorance" will likely be debatable in many
circumstances. Particularly because compliance programs are to be designed to give an
organization's managers significant, affirmative responsibilities in compliance oversight,
the Division is likely to pursue potential disqualifications on this ground vigorously.
Second, the Division will closely hold any
organization whose "substantial authority personnel" participated in an offense
to the burden the Guidelines place upon it of overcoming a presumption that its compliance
program simply was not effective. The Guidelines' definition of "substantial
authority personnel" appears to clearly encompass typical antitrust perpetrators -
individuals with authority to negotiate or set price levels or negotiate or approve
significant contracts. Thus, this presumption of ineffectiveness will likely become the
rule in antitrust cases, giving the Division as well as the court "show me"
status.
Third, the Division is unlikely to credit
largely "paper" compliance programs. one of the Division's principal concerns
during the development of the Guidelines chapter on organizational sentencing was that
substantial credit not be given for programs that rely primarily on memos enjoining
personnel not to commit antitrust violations. Price fixing and bid rigging are crimes
committed in bad faith, and compliance programs that rely on the good faith of those who
may see personal profit in secretive violations regardless of corporate policy will miss
the mark. Communicating corporate policy, standards and procedures regarding antitrust
compliance is, of course, an essential part of an effective program, but the Guidelines
require far more of an effort to qualify for fine reduction. Thus, the Division will not
favor programs that try to cover shortcomings in their other necessary elements with a
plethora of memoranda and meetings.
Fourth, affirmative steps to detect price
fixing or bid rigging, premised on the possibility or even the assumption that education
and admonition will not deter personnel who will act in bad faith, will be credited highly
by the Division. Active monitoring of employee conduct - of particular pricing and bidding
decisions and practices, for example will improve the chance of detecting and deterring
questionable conduct. The Division frequently monitors such practices in the course of its
investigations, and an organization's own ability to detect antitrust violations in this
manner is probably better than ours, as long as the organization's own detectives are
competent and reliable. Both regular and unannounced audits of price changes, discount
practices and bid sheets, conducted by those familiar with the firms past and
present business practices and trained in recognizing questionable divergence, would be
examples of creditable affirmative action. "Why was an item on a bid sheet so
high," and "why was a potential customer not bid at all are the types of
questions that salespersons and managers should expect to have to answer at any time. And
success measured by acceptable market share or increased profitability should not insulate
a person or corporate unit from such scrutiny - such results are fully consistent with the
typical goals of individual antitrust violators.
Fifth, both regular and unannounced audits
of the level of understanding of the antitrust law on the part of front-line pricing and
bidding personnel and their degree of compliance with a program's requirements relating to
prevention and detection, backed up by potential penalties, should be considered
invaluable adjuncts to initial employee antitrust sensitization. Important both initially
and during such audits is employee appreciation, not only of the relatively
straightforward matter of what constitutes price fixing and bid rigging, but also what
sorts of conversations, communications, or practices constitute suspect behavior.
Disabusing sales personnel of the notion that "business ethics" require
deference to existing customer-supplier relationships is one example of what such audits
might emphasize.
Sixth, the elements of a compliance
program, including particularly audits of the program itself and audits of pricing and
bidding practices, may be more highly valued if they are customized - designed and
targeted to the firm's specific organization and business practices. The Guidelines note
that an organization's failure to follow "industry practice" weighs against a
finding of an effective program to prevent and detect violations of law. At least in the
antitrust area, however, following by rote a generic industry-adopted compliance program
may be less effective than unique audits and other steps carefully tailored to the
antitrust pitfalls in an organization's own daily contexts.
Finally, the Division is likely to examine
closely the incentive structure of any compliance program that is proffered for credit
under the Guidelines. Strong negative incentives directed toward persons in positions
potentially to commit willful antitrust violations - perhaps loss of position, forfeiture
of benefits come immediately to mind, but less traditional negative and positive
incentives aimed at those charged with responsibility to detect and/or report violations
should also be considered. The Guidelines cite as a reasonable step to achieving
compliance putting in place and publicizing a reporting system whereby employees and other
agents can report criminal conduct by others without fear of retribution. An organization
seriously committed to deterring price fixing and bid rigging might emphasize the harm
that violations threaten to itself and thus to each and every employee, through carefully
designed penalties and rewards.
The Antitrust Division's views and
recommendations regarding compliance programs will surely become clearer and more specific
as such programs are integrated into antitrust sentencing. Its traditional resistance to
excusing antitrust violations entirely on the basis of proffered corporate good faith and
compliance programs, while likely to continue, will not lead the Division to downplay well
thought out and carried out programs; the Division will recommend giving credit where
credit is due. But if a compliance program boils down essentially to "we told them
not to," the Division is likely to be less than impressed.
Mr. Roberts is the Chief of the Legal
Policy Section of the Antitrust Division at the U.S. Department of Justice.